unable to tell if the bank failed for bank-specific or systemic reasons, so they become more reluctant to invest in the remaining banks. Anticipating such investor actions, banks try to minimise unfavourable information spill-overs of bank failures by investing in more highly correlated loans. Thus, the expectation of contagion causes banks to herd, which aggravates systemic risk and the magnitude of contagion occurring ex post. Nalebuff and Stiglitz (1983) examine the role of incentive conflicts in explaining herding.
18 See, for instance, Radner and Stiglitz (1984).
19 The general theory is set forth in Korinek (2008).
20 Alternatively, if contagion occurred through ârealâ channels â Mexican purchases of Argentinean goods were enhanced as a result of exchange rate support, because real balance effects are more important than relative price effects â then the Mexican intervention could reduce spill-over effects. These effects did not play an important role in the discussions preceding most of the bailouts.
21 Stiglitz (2010c) uses a life cycle model to show that capital market liberalisation may actually reduce the scope for inter-temporal risk sharing, and thus lower the long-term present discounted value of expected utility.
22 After each crisis of the 1980s and 1990s, policy makers identified a factor that seemed to be pivotal as the source of a crisis: an overvalued exchange rate, excessive public indebtedness, insufficient private savings, lack of transparency. But the analysis was ad hoc and had little predictive power. Mexicoâs problems in 1994 were markedly different from those of Latin America in the early 1980s. East Asian countries had high savings rates and low public indebtedness. The last set of countries to suffer from a financial crisis before the East Asian crisis were those of Scandinavia, generally viewed as the most transparent in the world. Furman and Stiglitz (1998) attempt to identify econometrically the factors that contribute to an economyâs vulnerability to a financial crisis. Needless to say, their results confirm the lack of predictive power of the standard explanations of vulnerability to a crisis.
References
Abreu, D. and Brunnermeier, M. (2003) âBubbles and Crashesâ, Econometrica , Vol. 71, No. 1, pp. 173â204.
Acharya, V. and Yorulmazer, T. (2008) âInformation Contagion and Bank Herdingâ, Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking , Vol. 40, No. 1, pp. 215â231.
Agenor, P.-R. and Masson, P. (1999) âCredibility, Reputation, and the Mexican Peso Crisisâ, Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking , Vol. 31, No. 1, pp. 70â84.
Allen, F. and Gale, D. (2000) âFinancial Contagionâ, Journal of Political Economy , Vol. 108, No. 1, pp. 1â33.
Banerjee, A. (1992) âA Simple Model of Herd Behaviorâ, Quarterly Journal of Economics , Vo. 107, No. 3, pp. 797â817.
Barberis, N. and Thaler, R. (2003) âA Survey of Behavioral Financeâ, in G. Constantinides, R. Stulz and M. Harris (eds.), Handbook of the Economics of Finance , Amsterdam: North-Holland, pp. 1053â1121.
Battiston, S., Delli Gatti, D., Greenwald, B. and Stiglitz, J. (2007) âCredit Chains and Bankruptcy Propagation in Production Networksâ, Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control , Vol. 31, No. 6, pp. 2061â2084.
Bernanke, B., Gertler, M. and Gilchrist, S. (1996) âThe Financial Accelerator and the Flight to Qualityâ, Review of Economics and Statistics , Vol. 78, No. 1, pp. 1â15.
Bikhchandani, S., Hirshleifer, D. and Welch, I. (1992) âA Theory of Fads, Fashion, Custom, and Cultural Change as Informational Cascadesâ, Journal of Political Economy , Vol. 100, No. 5, pp. 992â1026.
Caballero, R. and Krishnamurthy, A. (2001) âInternational and Domestic Collateral Constraints in a Model of Emerging Market Crisesâ, Journal of Monetary Economics , Vol. 48, No. 3, pp. 513â548.
Calvo,